Absolute advantage

In economics, the principle of absolute advantage refers to the ability of a party (an individual, or firm, or country) to produce a good or service more efficiently than its competitors.[1] Adam Smith first described the principle of absolute advantage in the context of international trade, using labor as the only input. Since absolute advantage is determined by a simple comparison of labor productiveness, it is possible for a party to have no absolute advantage in anything.[2]

Origin of the theory

The concept of absolute advantage is generally attributed to Adam Smith for his 1776 publication The Wealth of Nations in which he countered mercantilist ideas.[2][3] Smith argued that it was impossible for all nations to become rich simultaneously by following mercantilism because the export of one nation is another nation’s import and instead stated that all nations would gain simultaneously if they practiced free trade and specialized in accordance with their absolute advantage.[2] Smith also stated that the wealth of nations depends upon the goods and services available to their citizens, rather than their gold reserves.[4]

Because Smith only focused on comparing labor productivities to determine absolute advantage, he did not develop the concept of comparative advantage.[2] While there are possible gains from trade with absolute advantage, the gains may not be mutually beneficial. Comparative advantage focuses on the range of possible mutually beneficial exchanges.

Examples

Example 1

Figure 1
Hours of work necessary to produce one unit
Country Cloth Wine
UK 80 100
Portugal 120 90
Figure 2
Hours of work to commit after the specialization
Country Cloth Wine
UK 80 + 100 0
Portugal 0 90 + 120

According to Figure 1, the UK commits 80 hours of labor to produce one unit of cloth, which is fewer than Portugal's hours of work necessary to produce one unit of cloth. The UK is able to produce one unit of cloth with fewer hours of labor, therefore the UK has an absolute advantage in the production of cloth. On the other hand, Portugal commits 90 hours to produce one unit of wine, which is fewer than the UK's hours of work necessary to produce one unit of wine. Therefore, Portugal has an absolute advantage in the production of wine.

If the two countries specialize in producing the good for which they have the absolute advantage, and if they exchange part of the good with each other, both of the two countries can end up with more of each good than they would have in the absence of trade.[5][6] In the absence of trade, each country produces one unit of cloth and one unit of wine, i.e. a combined total production of 2 units of cloth and 2 units of wine. Here, if England commits all of its labor (80+100) for the production of cloth for which England has the absolute advantage, England produces (80+100)÷80=2.25 units of cloth. On the other hand, if Portugal commits all of its labor (90+120) for the production of wine, Portugal produces (90+120)÷90=2.33... units of wine. The combined total production in this case is 2.25 units of cloth and 2.33 units of wine which is greater than the total production of each good had there been no specialization. Assuming free trade this will lead to cheaper prices for both goods for both countries.

Example 2

You and your friends decided to help with fundraising for a local charity group by printing T-shirts and making birdhouses.

  • Scenario 1: One of your friends, Gina, can print 5 T-shirts or build 3 birdhouses an hour. Your other friend, Mike, can print 3 T-shirts an hour or build 2 birdhouses an hour. Because your friend Gina is more productive at printing T-shirts and building birdhouses compared to Mike, she has an absolute advantage in both printing T-shirts and building birdhouses.
  • Scenario 2: Suppose Gina wasn't as agile with the hammer and could only make 1 birdhouse an hour, but she took a screen printing class and could print 10 T-shirts an hour. Mike on the other hand takes woodworking and so he can build 5 birdhouses an hour, but he doesn't know the first thing about making T-shirts so he can only print 2 T-shirts an hour. While Gina would have the absolute advantage in printing shirts, Mike would have an absolute advantage in building birdhouses.

Further reading

  • Irwin, Douglas A. (1996). Against the Tide: An Intellectual History of Free Trade. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0691058962.
  • Smith, Adam (1776). An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations (Vol 1). ISBN 978-0865970069.
  • Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1954). History of economic analysis. Routledge. ISBN 9781134838707.
  • Trefler, Daniel (1995). "The Case of the Missing Trade and Other Mysteries". The American Economic Review. 85 (5): 1029–1046. JSTOR 2950973..

See also

References

  1. "Absolute advantage | economics". Encyclopedia Britannica. Retrieved 2020-10-21.
  2. "ABSOLUTE AND COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE" (PDF). INTERNATIONAL ENCYCLOPEDIA OF THE SOCIAL SCIENCES, 2ND EDITION. pp. 1–2. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2010-05-29. Retrieved 2009-05-04.
  3. International Trade: Theory and Policy.
  4. Harrington, James W. "International Trade Theory". Geography 349 Absolute advantage. University of Washington. Retrieved 2009-05-04.
  5. Bruce Bueno de Mesquita (2013), Principles of International Politics, SAGE, pp. 329–330, ISBN 9781483304663
  6. Teofilo C. Daquila (2005), The Economies of Southeast Asia: Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, and Thailand, Nova Publishers, p. 124, ISBN 9781594541889


This article is issued from Wikipedia. The text is licensed under Creative Commons - Attribution - Sharealike. Additional terms may apply for the media files.